Here at HR, we like to present both sides of the argument when it comes to markets.

When it comes to politics, we like to present both sides of the story (hey look, it’s not our fault that the political story is one-sided right now – after all, we didn’t write it).

Unfortunately, we can’t say the same for some other popular commentators. True, everyone is biased (we certainly are) and everyone has an agenda (we certainly do), but despite what some readers say, we don’t push our biases nearly as hard as most other outlets that do what we do. Just today for instance, we published a great guest post on why European stocks could be set for an epic melt up (i.e. a bullish post).

Well, in the true spirit of keeping coverage balanced, we thought it would be a good idea to highlight the latest from Bloomberg’s Cameron Crise, who notes that contrary to popular belief, central bank liquidity from the ECB and the BoJ may not have that much of an effect on US yields after all.

Now needless to say, we’re skeptical and by “skeptical” we mean “on the verge of calling bullshit,” (what happens when you account for GCC and EM FX reserve accumulation?), but as Crise notes, “it’s always a good idea to challenge preconceived notions by delving into the data [and while] we sometimes find our convictions are strengthened, [other times] we find an answer other than the one we’re looking for.”

Via Bloomberg

While the Fed moves slowly toward shrinking its balance sheet, neither the ECB nor BOJ seem interested at the moment in slowing the expansion of theirs. What does the ongoing expansion of global liquidity mean for Treasury investors? It turns out the answer may be “not much.”

  • In performing financial market research, sometimes your investigations take you in the opposite direction from the one you intend. In setting out to demonstrate that ongoing QE in Europe and Japan would keep a lid on Treasury yields, I found that they don’t matter that much one way or another.
  • I regressed the US 10-year yield against a range of variables: core PCE inflation, the unemployment rate, the Fed funds rate, and Fed expectations proxied by the slope of the 2nd vs 6th eurodollar contracts. I ran three separate studies: one with just these variables, one with the size of the Fed balance sheet, and one with the combined size of the G3 central-bank balance sheets.
  • I expected to find a lower model projection using the balance sheet input. In fact, there was virtually no difference between the model outputs, with stable coefficients across the other variables. Currently the gap between the model with the G3 balance sheets and that with none is about 20 bps.