Image Source: PexelsThe increasing role of intangible assets compared to physical assets in our economy has been accompanied by increased research into their impact on asset prices and returns. Studies such as the 2020 papers “Explaining the Recent Failure of Value Investing,” “Intangible Capital and the Value Factor: Has Your Value Definition Just Expired?,” and “Explaining the Recent Failure of Value Investing,” ,” and the 2023 paper “Explaining the Recent Failure of Value Investing,” ” have found that the increasing importance of intangibles, at least for industries with high concentrations of them, is playing an essential role in the cross-section of returns.Since the development of the CAPM, academic research has attempted to find models that increase the explanatory power of the cross-section of stock returns. We moved from the single-factor CAPM to the three-factor Fama-French model (adding size and value), to the Carhart four-factor model (adding momentum), to Lu Zhang’s
q-factor model (beta, size, investment, profitability), to the Fama-French five-factor (adding value to the q-factor model) and six-factor models (adding back value and momentum to the q-factor model). There have also been versions that use different metrics for profitability and value, and Explaining the Recent Failure of Value Investing,” . Regardless of the model used, an anomaly for all models is that the empirical evidence demonstrates that stocks with high research and development (R&D) expenses have delivered a premium.The Role of R&DResearch on the role of R&D expenditures, including the 2004 study “Valuation and Return Dynamics of New Ventures” and the 2020 studies “Mispricing or Risk Premium? An Explanation of the R&D-to-Market Anomaly,” “The R&D Anomaly: Risk or Mispricing?,” and “Explaining the Recent Failure of Value Investing,” ” has found:
In their January 2023 study, “Explaining the Recent Failure of Value Investing,” ,” Sunil Wahal and Amit Goyal found:
Latest ResearchKevin Tseng contributes to the literature with his January 2022 study, “Explaining the Recent Failure of Value Investing,” ,” in which he examined how learning about new technology through technology spillover impacts asset prices and returns. He began by noting:
“Technological innovation is a key driver of long-term economic growth, and technologically innovative firms constitute a large share of the stock market in the United States. One of the characteristics of innovation is the non-excludability that allows a firm to learn technologically related information from its peers. … Technology spillover enables firms to learn from peers’ successes or failures as they simultaneously face their own uncertainties about technology prospects. Theoretical models that explain learning about new technology suggest that technology spillover, in the presence of technical uncertainty, enables firms to implement new technology timelier, thereby making large-scale technology adoption possible. Both this timelier adoption of new technology and a higher likelihood of large-scale technology adoption make the risks associated with technological innovation more systematic. These theoretical models then, importantly, imply that learning about new technology through technology spillover should impact asset prices.”
Tseng added: “In theory, firms face uncertainty when deciding if and when to implement new technology, as technology spillover enables firms to learn from peers’ successes or failures. This learning provides firms with more precise information about the new technology, which they then use to determine when (and the scale to which) they should adopt this new, profit-generating technology.”To test whether firms with higher spillover earn higher returns in the cross-section, Tseng constructed empirical measures of spillover based on the amount of technological information a firm receives from its peers—measuring technology spillover using the patent-technology-weighted sum of peer firms’ R&D stocks. He explained:
“These patent-technology weights, or technology relatedness, reflect the notion that a firm learns more from technologies produced by other firms with patent-technology patterns similar to its own.”
Tseng’s sample consisted of patents granted from 1976 to 2006 from the updated National Bureau of Economic Research site, data of patents granted from 2007 to 2009 from the authors of the 2012 study “Technological Innovation, Resource Allocation, and Growth,” and hand-collected patents granted from 2010 to 2014 from Google Patent and later manually matched with Compustat. He included NYSE, AMEX, and Nasdaq-listed securities, excluding firms in the financial and utilities sectors. To construct the technology spillover measure, he required that firms have at least one patent granted in the past five years. His sample spanned the period 1982-2014. Here is a summary of his key findings:
Technology Spillover of IndustriesThis table reports the pooled mean (Mean), median (Median), standard deviation (Stdev), 1st percentile (P1), 5th percentile (P5), 25th percentile (P25), 75th percentile (P75), 95th percentile (P95), and 99th percentile (P99) of the technology spillover measure for firms in industries based on the Fama-French 17 industry classification system. Financial and utility firms are excluded. Technology spillover (in billions of dollars) is computed by using the procedure described in Section 3.1 (based on the BSV approach). The sample period is 1982 to 2014.The results are hypothetical results and are NOT an indicator of future results and do NOT represent returns that any investor actually attained. Indexes are unmanaged and do not reflect management or trading fees, and one cannot invest directly in an index.
Providing robust support for his findings, Tseng found that legislation that decreased spillover effects (such as the staggered passage of the Uniform Trade Secrets Act and the staggered adoption of the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine) lessened the spillover effect. In contrast, legislation (such as the Inventor Protection Act, which was found to accelerate patent disclosures by an average of 11 months) that increased the spillover effect strengthened it.Tseng’s findings led him to conclude: “Firms with higher levels of technology spillover have higher stock returns in the cross-section. These results are robust to alternative measures of technology spillover and to controls of known return predictors.” He added:
“My findings support the implication that technology spillover enables firms to learn about and subsequently adopt new technology in the presence of technology-based uncertainty. The timelier adoption of new technology and the higher likelihood of large-scale technology adoption make the risk associated with technological innovation more systematic, which in turn increases returns required by investors for technology spillover recipients.”
Investor TakewaysSupported by the findings of a significant positive relationship between R&D expenditures and future stock returns and the risk-based explanations for the R&D, the empirical research suggests a fundamentally important role of intellectual capital, specifically R&D, in asset pricing—the higher returns to high R&D stocks represent compensation for heightened systematic risk not captured in standard asset pricing models.Tseng contributed to the literature that explores financial market implications of intangibles, showing that technology spillover is an important externality of intangibles—excess returns accrue not only to firms with high R&D themselves but also to those whose peers engage in R&D. He also provided support for a risk-based explanation for the R&D premium: Innovation is risky.More By This Author:How Cheap Are Value Stocks?The Quality Factor — What Exactly Is It?The Challenge Facing ESG Investors
Leave A Comment